Iceland and the impact of a trade war

Apparently, Iceland will fare better under the newly announced US tariffs than many neighbouring countries will. From a global standpoint, a trade war will probably weaken GDP growth and push inflation higher. For Iceland specifically, inflation could prove more stubborn in the short run, necessitating a slower monetary easing phase, but those effects would probably recede over time.


Why is a trade war a bad idea?

Tariffs affect national economies in various ways, and their footprint far exceeds the direct impact on the price of goods to producers and consumers, although prices usually get the most attention. Tariffs are taxes and trade barriers rolled into one, and they usually deliver a one-two punch, owing to the combined effect of these two types of interference in economic activity.

This includes the following:

  • Higher consumer prices. The price of imported consumer goods and imported inputs rises in the country imposing the tariffs.
  • Inefficient allocation of resources. Capital and labour are used for inefficient domestic activities.
  • Erosion of alliances. Allied countries respond in kind, scaling down communications and cooperation with the instigating country.
  • Increased inequality. Goods hit by tariffs generally constitute a larger share of poorer people’s consumption basket, so lower-income consumers suffer a bigger drop in living standards than wealthier people do.
  • Drain on time and effort. A significant amount of time is wasted on tariff-related bureaucracy and oversight. A more complicated tariff structure leads to more waste than would otherwise occur.
  • Disincentive for progress and advancement. “Protected” sectors have less incentive to mature and enhance efficiency when they are sheltered behind tariff barriers.
  • Creation of unhealthy incentives. Substantial time and money are spent circumventing rules and regulations, lobbying for demarcated tariff relief in specified sectors, and finding ways to minimise the inconvenience and inefficiency associated with tariffs in complex supply chains.
  • Reduction in prosperity. Slower advancements in manufacturing, inefficient use of resources, and waste owing to many of the above-mentioned factors ultimately cut into GDP growth and reduce prosperity among the general public.

In spite of the aforementioned drawbacks, it is possible to argue in favour of limited tariffs and trade barriers in individual sectors, based on perspectives such as food security, energy security, defence, or regional policies. Experience has shown, however, that such arguments are made far more often than is warranted.

Uncertainty makes a bad situation worse

It is no exaggeration to say that it has proven difficult to pinpoint the purpose and ultimate scope of the tariffs the US authorities have either announced or signalled. Three arguments have been made at various times by various representatives of the government:

  • Revenue generation for the US Treasury: The US authorities have asserted that revenues from tariffs could offset losses stemming from tax cuts.
  • Furtherance of domestic manufacturing: In recent decades, a significant amount of manufacturing has been moved out of the US as developing countries has become industrialised and trade and manufacturing have become globalised. The US authorities want to reverse this trend.
  • Response to other countries’ unfair business practices: The US has a sizeable goods trade deficit with the rest of the world. The American authorities blame this on trade barriers, government subsidies of manufacturing in other countries, and manipulation of currency exchange rates against the US dollar, and they want to use tariffs as a negotiating tool in a bid to level the playing field.

Explaining all of the flaws in these arguments is a topic that certainly warrants separate discussion, but it would take far too much time and space here. Furthermore, some of these objectives are at odds with one another; for instance, if tariff-generated revenues decline as domestic manufacturing grows at the expense of imports. On the other hand, the kaleidoscope of contradictory objectives presented as grounds for the tariffs, the rapid changes in the tariffs proposed, and the lack of advance notice about the changes have greatly exacerbated uncertainty about the economic outlook, sending global markets reeling. Notwithstanding the most recent developments in the drama, this uncertainty is far from being a thing of the past, and it continues to compound the damage done by the tariff regime.

As long as uncertainty prevails about the global trade barrier landscape, the risk exists that companies will postpone investment decisions, which could ultimately throw sand in the gears of GDP growth, both in the US and worldwide. The same can be said of households’ consumption spending, as individuals will presumably avoid big-ticket purchases such as cars, home appliances, and overseas travel during a period of this much uncertainty. Expectations surveys taken among US consumers and company executives have shown greater pessimism about the economic outlook and more pronounced concerns about inflation.

How will this affect the global economy?

As long as uncertainty prevails about the path a possible trade war will take, it is impossible to speculate about the economic impact it will have, either globally or in Iceland. The OECD has published an interesting scenario analysis in a recent macroeconomic forecast. The forecast includes a scenario assuming a flat 10% tariff on non-commodity imports to the US and commensurate retaliatory tariffs imposed by all other countries. The OECD’s baseline forecast actually entails some impact from the tariffs already announced in March and assumes somewhat slower GDP growth and more persistent inflation than its previous forecast. It should also be borne in mind that, on average, the tariffs announced thus far by the US are higher than the 10% assumed by the OECD.

As the chart suggests, the estimated negative on GDP growth in advanced economies (the backbone of the OECD) are considerably stronger on the US itself than on the global economy as a whole. The trade war will also deliver quite a blow to Canada and Mexico, while the impact on the eurozone and the largest countries in Asia is projected to be much more modest. The estimated impact on the US is markedly greater than on other advanced economies, which hardly aligns with the purpose of the tariffs as described by the US authorities.

Moreover, the OECD considers the possibility of far more persistent global inflation a key risk in connection with the trade war, particularly for countries in North America. In the end, it would also spread to Iceland, as the transmission of foreign prices to domestic inflation is quite strong, and imported goods account for a large share of Icelanders’ consumption basket. If inflation develops as is sketched out in the OECD scenario, central banks will be in a bit of a bind, and policy rates in Iceland and abroad could temporarily be higher as a result.

Tariffs on Iceland are more moderate than on neighbouring countries

It appears that the tariffs announced by the US authorities on 2 April were calculated as a ratio of the goods trade deficit to each country’s total goods exports. The tariffs on Iceland therefore fall into the lowest category, 10%, as Iceland has generally run a small goods account deficit vis-à-vis the US. For comparison, EU countries are faced with a 20% tariff, and Norwegian goods imported to the US will carry a 15% tariff.

On this front, the fact that the US should focus solely on goods trade is of benefit to Iceland. As for services trade, Iceland has been running a handsome surplus vis-à-vis the US in recent years, owing mainly to Americans’ keen interest in travelling to Iceland. In 2024, more than one of every four tourists visiting the country came from the US, with other countries trailing far behind.

Last year, Iceland was a net importer of US goods to the tune of slightly over ISK 6bn, whereas its net exports of services to the US totalled ISK 219bn for the same period.

Fish, pharmaceuticals, and medical products the mainstay of exports to the US

Although the US is an important trading partner for Iceland, its share in Iceland’s goods exports is relatively modest, at 12% (ISK 110bn) in 2024. Seafood and healthcare-related goods account for the vast majority of these exports. Exports of fish came to ISK 46bn last year. Cod accounted for nearly half, although haddock and farmed salmon exports weighed heavily as well. Just over ISK 39bn worth of exported goods were classified by Statistics Iceland (SI) as medical products and equipment. That category includes drugs manufactured by Alvotech, Oculis, and others; products such as wound dressings produced by Kerecis; prosthetics and support gear made by Össur; and sleep research equipment made by Nox Medical. It should be noted that aluminium, which constitutes a large share of Iceland’s exported goods, is sold almost entirely to Europe and is therefore not directly affected by the tariffs. In addition, pharmaceuticals are exempt from the tariff regime, at least for the time being, which should come as a relief to Icelandic pharmaceuticals companies that sell drugs to the US.

The impact of a trade war on Iceland is highly uncertain

It is exceedingly difficult to project with any certainty what impact the tariffs already announced by the US will ultimately have on the Icelandic economy. Even so, there are a few points that will be of critical importance going forward.

First, Government authorities must make every effort to ensure that Iceland’s trade with its main trading partners remains free of tariffs and other barriers insofar as is possible. Leaders of several key countries have responded to the newly announced tariffs by threatening to impose their own tariffs on goods imported from the US. Thus far, these responses have centred on measures vis-à-vis the US rather than on broad-based tariffs on imports from trading partners.

If tariffs on Iceland’s exports are largely limited to the US, there will be correspondingly less impact on domestic inflation. Furthermore, it will be easier for exporters to sell their goods – marine products, for instance – to large markets other than the US, without suffering significant losses. Moreover, it bodes well that the Icelandic authorities appear determined to address this issue firmly, and as yet there are few indications that Iceland will end up squeezed between trade barriers on both sides, although the possibility cannot be excluded.

It is virtually beyond doubt that the tariffs will have a negative impact on demand and GDP growth in Iceland, although certain sectors or companies may benefit from proportionally low tariffs in a global context. We think it quite likely, though, that the blow to the Icelandic economy will not be too onerous, as long as a full-blown trade war does not completely change the world trade environment.

One major uncertainty concerns the impact on American tourists’ interest in visiting Iceland. Recent surveys carried out in the US suggest that Americans are very keen to travel. That could change, however, if the adverse effects of the tariffs start to cut into US households’ disposable income in the coming term. A significant contraction in US nationals’ travel to Iceland would quickly chip away at the tourism industry, which is already facing greater near-term uncertainty than was envisioned at the start of the year.

As regards the impact on inflation and the policy rate, the picture is murkier. Inflation will probably be affected in two ways:

  • As is noted above, the global price level affects domestic inflation fairly strongly, through what is called imported inflation. We therefore think it more likely that a trade war’s short-term impact on key trading blocs would be to push inflation higher in Iceland.
  • Further ahead, however, a tariff-related downturn in economic activity will probably ease global inflationary pressures, which, together with the potential dampening effect on demand and exports in Iceland, could gradually offset the aforementioned cost effects and even overtake them if the trade war proves onerous and protracted.

In the quarters immediately ahead, inflation could turn out higher than it might otherwise, perhaps prompting the Central Bank (CBI) to lower interest rates more slowly. These effects should reverse later on, however, and falling inflation and a larger slack in the economy should make it easier for the CBI to stay the course and keep unwinding the policy stance.

Analyst


Jón Bjarki Bentsson

Chief economist


Contact